Private Banking Sector example essay topic

4,576 words
The Structure of a Financial Crisis Lessons from Turkey BY AY BEK GOREY ( ) INTRODUCTION The year 2001 had been unlucky for Turkey. Apart from the crisis in 1994 and November 2000, the country had to face another financial crisis, causing problems in the management of its economy. Why does a country delve deep into financial crisis? What are the possible immediate triggers for both the current and potential new crises? What precautions should be taken for the key issues like the fragility of the financial and banking system, belated reforms and privatisation, rampant corruption, exchange rate policy?

And how can the governments satisfy the markets and people to undertake these reforms? The current crisis has not hit the country overnight. This article figures out the weakness of the system, years of neglect and mismanagement, possible solutions for other developing countries. One has to bear in my mind that even evaluating the aftermath of the 1994 crisis, Turkey was a rising star, with aspirations towards full membership to the European Union. Among the potential applicants of EU membership, - mostly the Transition Economies of Eastern Europe- Turkey was the mere applicant with a functioning Customs Union with the EU back in 1995. With a relatively large and dynamic market, having high hopes for rapid economic and social progress, Turkey seemed a valuable candidate for the European Integration.

Now after the 2000 November and 2001 February crises, the shrinking of the economy suggests that Turkey can only catch up with the figures of year 2000, as far as the year 2004, let alone the EU membership and further growth. To indicate why such a failure has been suffered, we have to go back to the roots of mismanagement. And that begins with the problems of Privatisation practices. THE INITIATION OF PRIVATISATION Privatisation has proved to be a successful method for improving institutions and maintaining corporate efficiency all around the world.

But under certain conditions either privatized firms can get into serious difficulties or delaying the privatisation programs could trigger economic crises, together with the impact caused by years of mismanagement, not undertaking the progressive reforms and corruption - as experienced in some of the transition economies of Eastern Europe, Central Asia, Far East, and as is the case in this article, in Turkey THE FIRST DECADE OF SUCCESS The past decade forced the public sector to its knees, all around the world. Though Turkey was not a transition economy, the winds of change has affected the public sector like in all other developed and developing economies. However, unlike the Transition Economies, Turkey embarked on a prospective plan to privatize a major part of the public sector in the mid 80's and laws enacting and enabling the privatisation of the State Owned Enterprises (SOE) in late 1985, was an important breakthrough. In the 1990's privatisation went ahead but caused disappointment in many sectors. Most privatized firms could not improve their performance and some that succeeded, had been profitable already as SOEs. But that was not the only problem the country had to face.

Turkey had already begun to face significant problems regarding the Privatisation Policy in the 1990's. These mentioned problems not only aroused from the aggregate demand concerning the SOE, and the negative effect of investment but the ongoing debate carried by the opposing political parties in the Parliament. The governments have overcome several difficulties and successfully resumed privatisation in the beginning of the second decade. Though the outcome was promising, the program proceeded more slowly than the original plan. In 1993 for example, a net revenue of US$543 millions was raised through several privatized firms including two electric companies, two communications equipment manufacturers, a supermarket chain and four cement factories. In 1994 a total of approximately US$412 million was raised through the sale of an automobile manufacturer, remaining cement factories by international offering resulted in US$330 Million.

In 1995, a total of US$573 million was raised. Sales during this year included entities in the sugar, cement and magnesium industries, as well as a state bank. In 1996, a total of approximately US$300 million resulting from disposal of entities in the cement, zinc, forestry and textile industries had been realised. TABLETABLEPRIVATISATION GROSS REVENUES. The new legislation established the Privatisation High Council (PHC) for presenting proposals and determining plans. A critical turning point was reached when the privatisation plan for Turk Telecom was proposed.

Under the new Privatisation Law in May, 1995, Turk Telecom shares were decided to be privatized. And in June 1995, Turk Telecom was reserved into the privatisation portfolio and studies for further assessment have begun. On February 28, 1996, the Constitutional Court annulled and banned the execution of some articles of Law No: 4107. As a result of this decision, PHC had no longer reserves the authority for transferring and selling the shares. The tender process of advisory services of Turk Telecom was cancelled. After completion the necessary amendments on August 5, 1996 a new law has been enacted.

In accordance with this law, 49% of Telecom (TT AS) shares were announced to be privatized as follows; 10% assigned for the Directorate General of Postal's, 5% to employees, 34% to strategic investors and equity offering The international consortium leaded by Goldman Sachs was chosen as the consultant firm in the evaluation process of Turkish Telecom and an agreement was signed under these terms. But the Constitutional Court has rejected the petition for cancellation of some articles of the Law regarding the reform and privatisation of Turk Telecom. This rejection, while eliminating further obstacles for the privatisation of Turk Telecom, may be considered a turning point for further economic reform and financial liberalization in Turkey, because it was the inauguration of an era in which Domestic Politics affected the Privatisation Program negatively. Had Turk Telecom been privatized in that period, it was expected to raise revenue a few times more than the whole 1986-1995 period and thus encourage the rest of the privatisation program to be realised, including the large state banks. But even in early 2002, new plans are still effortlessly undertaken to privatize Turk Telecom, yet the revenue expected is far lower than the first enactment date due to the changing market trends in the international markets.

2) THE NEARING CRISIS major problem of the Turkish economy -- shared with many of the transition and developing economies -- is the high inflation rate. In a low inflation rate economy, the income redistribution effect of privatisation is substantial, thus can gain large public support. In many developed economies, including the most obvious example in Britain, unlike the developing economies, privatisation had clearly improved both the overall economic performance and corporate efficiency. In the developed countries, even the privatized large firms have marginal consequences in terms of the whole economy. Government interference had been minimise d thanks to the relatively transparency of the process. Most economies with high inflation rates also suffer from rampant corruption, so neither efficiency nor transparency can be maintained in these countries.

Corrupt management practices prevent a radical reform of corporate management. And the slowdown of economic growth affects the public negatively. Following the Turk Telecom failure, in 1999, the negotiations for the privatisation of several large SOEs was still going on. Yet the major reason for the economic crisis that occurred in 2001 - and is still continuing with several impacts - was proved to be the banking sector. The Turkish private banking sector went awry rapidly; and many banks - some of them privatized in the last decade- were gutted of their funds; illegal loans were thought to be granted; while the bank owners were accused of transferring money to their own companies - some of which were again privatized in the last decade- and capital was completely wasted due to the loans not being repaid.

A number of bank owners were taken into custody for questioning and even formally arrested and charged; and banks went into state receivership overnight. These momentous operations resulted in new regulations for the banking & financial sector. Nineteen private banks, which were thought to have been robbed and whose capital structures were found out to be fragile, were turned over to the Savings Deposits Insurance Fund (SDIF). A new Institution called as BBR (Board of Banking Regulations) was installed to inspect and audit the operations of SDIF. The government's aim was to strengthen the capital structures of these banks and sell the appropriate ones immediately.

During the process various banks merged under the same roof and the government succeeded in selling some of these banks. The net gains from these selling operations helped to net approximately $20 billion for SDIF. But the need for deeper reforms in the financial sector has assumed much greater urgency since the dramatic crises of November 2000 and February 2001. The economic crisis created by the somewhat poor state of governance in the financial sector, has brought to a boil the long simmering potential of the sector to undermine macroeconomic stability.

Inasmuch as the gradual balance sheet strengthening of the large state banks, prior to their privatisation dominated concerns until recently, the need to analyse and solve the crisis in private banking seems to impose very large fiscal costs on the budget. The impact of the crisis on inflation control proved to be grave. Turkey experienced another failure of an exchange rate-based stabilization, originally a three year program announced approximately 14 months prior to the February 2001 crisis. The principal aim of the government was to end high inflation dominating the economy for two decades. The government was forced in February 2001 to abandon the currency peg at once, which had been based the anchor of the fiscal strategy, thus sparking an immediate devaluation of the national currency, the lira, by around 32% in the following week. The program had started out with unprecedented political backing, managed to achieve some highly impressive initial results and the public opinion widely held provided a far better chance of prosperity than several previous internationally supported programs.

Yet the outcome was the worst failure in the history of the country. Considering past events, it's clearly figured out that the weakened banking system and tendency to over-reliance on inflows of hot money left the country defenceless and highly vulnerable to potential crises of confidence. This has resulted in the currency peg's failure to hold position when the inevitable tensions of such a rapid adjustment emerged. The unpredicted devaluation delayed the government's plan and promise to achieve single-digit inflation.

The simultaneous interest rate increase and the banks' liquidity preference indicted large bank balance sheet losses and severe fiscal stress. The tensions climaxed in a crisis first in late November 2000. This first crisis was also deeply rooted in the country's lacking economic system, but the primary cause of the stress was a mixture of the banks' portfolio losses and liquidity problems in a few banks, which addressed a loss of confidence in the entire banking system both in the markets and public eye, as well as the foreign investors. The Central Bank then acted to inject massive liquidity into the system, violating its own quasi-currency board rules effective for several decades, it created fears that the program and currency peg were no longer sustainable, and the extra liquidity merely flowed out through the capital account and drained reserves.

This first panic was arrested only with a $7.5 billion IMF emergency funding package which is over and above the original and standard $4 billion stand-by loan. Then the coalition government backed and reaffirmed the commitment to the previous inflation package expectations, promised to speed up privatisation efforts and financial sector reforms, eventually took over a major bank assumed to be the origin of the current liquidity problems, and announced a new and unpredicted guarantee for all liabilities of the banking sector, either private or state owned. The grave situation experienced seemed to stabilize by January 2001, while the government claimed nearly all of the $6 billion that had assumed to exit the domestic markets in the crisis flowed back and national reserves were again reconstituted. Nonetheless, the investors were now demanding incredibly higher interest rates as compared with these before the crisis, while indicating an upward shift in the current country risk premium.

What's more, virtually the recent capital inflow was fixed on short-terms, mostly overnight basis, deprived of suggestions towards a possible residual devaluation fear. The investors' confidence in the ongoing programme was not positively restored, despite several government pronouncements and IMF support. In this defined critical financial environment, a public row between President and Prime Minister occurred on February 19 2001, seemingly centred on the President's anti-corruption campaign, at once guided the way to the perception that the governing coalition and consequently the programme was threatened and found deciphered. Renewed crisis followed. Nevertheless, the Central Bank stuck well to its quasi-currency board rules, seemed reluctant to act as lender of last chance, and assumed that banks would be eager to expend their foreign exchange reserves for the purpose of obtaining national currency.

However this misadministration resulted in record overnight interest rates, peaking at approximately 5000% on February 21. The banking system, already intensely depressed by the first crisis, faced a terrible breakdown as the markets experienced the interbank payments system's ceasing to function altogether. The following day the distressed coalition government concluded a floating for lira, and publicly announced the official end of the exchange rate-based stabilization programme. Free floating of the currency was presumably the only convenient solution.

The market confidence that would have been required to sustain the crawling peg strategy was not present. Acknowledging this certainty as soon as possible has allowed the government to initiate such floating regime with most of the intact possible reserves, instead of depleting them in a futile attempt to defend the peg. The authorities were forced to initiate anew to plan the outlines of a programme in light of the new currency framework. 3) THE IMPACT ON THE STATE & PRIVATE BANKS Consequential quasi-fiscal programs mandating the large state banks to provide subsidies and preferential credit highly influenced by short term domestic politics, led to significant accumulation of government obligations to the state banks which has shown to increase from 2.2 percent of GNP in 1995 to 13 percent of GNP by 1999. The so - called problem of 'duty losses" is being addressed through measures taken to solely the existing stock of duty losses and to merely phase out substantial credit subsidies and fully budget for any duty losses in 2002. With the cost of money increasing, the real sector could not produce properly due to the lacking bank loans and some other negative events in the economy.

When all circles accepted that economic stability could not be provided in an environment in which there was no production, the real sector and the government held long meetings and tried to find solutions for the problems of the real sector and regulations to increase production. Nonetheless, the quasi-fiscal operation had a high cost repugnant impact on the state banks and thus on the budget. The lack of liquidity experienced in these two huge state banks resulted in increasing costs and delayed remuneration for the huge amount of duty losses which were imposed as part of the governmental quasi-fiscal policy contributed to distortions in the financial market. These mentioned two state banks concluded to borrow liquidity in the overnight market and from the Central Bank, and this was a very risky step, merely increasing the costs especially in the aftermath of the financial crises of November 2000 and February 2001. It has to be noted that between the crucial years 1995 and 1999, these two banks received only 10 percent of their total duty loss amount due from government. However the inconsistency continued after February and in May 2001, both banks were first estimated and then judged to be unable to pay their outstanding debts.

The settlement of the outstanding government liabilities to the two banks and the relatively costs of injecting new capital in order to reach 8 percent capital adequacy imposed a consequential burden on the new budget. But back in early December 2000, the government had introduced a new legislation to privatize the three main state banks Ziraat Bank, Halkbank and Emlakbank (the Housing Credit Bank which was amalgamated later into Ziraat Bank) The Parliament eagerly approved the legislation, but concluded in enabling the restructuring of the banks prior to privatisation. A critical article of this legislation obliged the state banks not to undertake 'duties' not having the suitable compensation included in the new budget. The privatisation of Ziraat and Half banks would arouse new hopes to remove the vicious cycle of the quasi- fiscal policy, but these dreams have turned sour. The apparent lesson from this experience is that the non-transparency inherent in such a deep rooted quasi-fiscal policy would result in frustrating and costly consequences both for the financial sector and the budget. By the summer of 2001 total budgetary outlays for re-capitalizing all three state banks had reached to approximately 25 Billion US$.

As the handicapped quasi-fiscal relationship between government and state banks carried significant risks, the government was also denounced to risks from the rest of the banking and financial sector mostly from the private banks as a result of an extensive environment mismanagement, and accountability. Subsequent to the 1994-95 banking crisis, the government had initiated a very risky 100 percent deposit insurance scheme for household deposits, and thus caused a moral hazard. Implicitly large contingent liabilities were then tied to the fluctuating health of the financial sector. The threatening result was the rapid growth of the banking system with assets of US$58 billion in late 1994 rising to US$156 billion in late 2000. Nonetheless, judicious regulations were insufficient and enforcement was significantly weak. This resulted in various banking practices which caused an increase in the liability of the banking system to the interest rates and more important exchange rate behaviour's.

Incautious banking practices like, deficiency in diversification and disproportionate exposure to foreign currency risk, non-performing loans going unchecked, and the insider lending and criminal frauds committed added new risks. Then government attempted to rehabilitate the public banking sector. 4) THE NEW BANKING LAW The government focused on a new draft law on banking aiming effectively at the deferral of the debts of companies affected by the crisis and the strengthening of the financial structures. The new law was passed after a long debate of concerns regarding the so - called 'Bank Rescuing'. The law assured that state resources would be given to banks whose capitals were found unsatisfactory. Nevertheless, the owners of the bank will add to the capital the equivalent of the resource provided by the state.

With the relevant cost of money increasing, the real sector could not achieve proper standards of production. Let's see what the new law is bringing briefly and what the reaction from the bank owners's ide is. o The government assures to provide financial support to private banks which satisfy a five to nine percent capital ratio. The assured support will be provided through the SDIF. The banks having a capital ratio under five percent need to have more than one percent share in the market to be covered by the law. o The State, prior to the contribution to a bank's capital, will carry out separate inspections of the bank's balance sheets taking 31/12/2001 as the base. o Ziraat Bank and Halkbank will have additional credits of US$1 billion to use aside from the credits proposed to be given to craftsmen, tradesmen, farmers and companies of small and medium size. o Public sector banks will not be allowed to become partners with companies which have been clearly identified as indebted. This will provide getting measures that block transparency. o Sixty percent of the support given to the banks will be provided to the real sector until June 30, 2003. The state will be a shareholder in proportion to how much it gave to the bank; however the bank owner will provide as much money as the state has provided as capital.

The shares that the bank owner has placed in his bank will be held as security against the shares that the state has put in and will be kept in the SDIF's safe. o The legal and penal responsibilities of public sector bank officials will be the equal of similar officials in private banks. But the banks have been reported to be reluctant in accepting this last offer of the government, which will result in the State's taking over new banks. This seems like a very interesting yet puzzling fact, but many banks in both the developed and the developing nations have faced such rescue packages, tough their response and reaction varies. The recapitalization introduces the State as a big shareholder and partner which seems a grave situation for private banks.

Another problem arouses from the concerns of the bank owners regarding the bank's reputation. However, the government is insistent on this law, so we may assume coercion would be possible as experienced in Asian countries like Japan, Malaysia and Thailand whose private banks in difficulty were reluctant in the very near future. CONCLUSIONS - LESSONS LEARNED In the aftermath of the February 2001 crisis, the government was forced to accelerate financial sector restructuring. The government authorities had no other choice but to attempt to limit the damage with prudent macro-economic policies, and word out solutions for banking & financial system, restore the market, gain public and investor confidence by a determined and continued implementation of a very detailed structural reform and speeding up the current privatisation programmes. So, we can now clearly classify and underline the lessons learned during the financial crisis in Turkey. o The first lesson is not only proceeding with current privatisation programs, but also improving the quality and balancing between an exaggerated speed up and a harmful slowdown, delaying or postponing. Governments should perform their best to reorganise the public sector, enable new regulations to prevent quasi - fiscal policies executed for the sake of favoritism, especially regarding public owned banks.

That should be noted a very effective way of reducing the stress on the public budget. o The second lesson is the significant overvaluation of the local currency. If the monetary and governmental authorities seem unwilling to let the local currency float freely, and devaluation in an orderly and healthy way problems are likely to form. However, determining the level of the overvaluation will require a subjective judgement freed from domestic politics and party values. Otherwise, cheap populism ends with a greater damage for the masses.

And the financial crisis is likely to continue until the so called 'undervaluation' of the local currency attracts speculators, investors and other market players including small investors and even masses. o The third lesson we learn is the actual, extremely rapid and considerable increase of short- term external (and in this case) internal debts. One of the grave pitfalls of the governments in Turkey had been the tendency and practice of financing the account deficit with short term external debts. Any country facing foreign borrowing should optimism it with long term debts, if applicable. Also even the long term debts should not be used in financing deficits (if possible of course), thus investment in real or service sectors should be maintained. If short term debts are introduced into the system as a deficit financing instrument, and relied upon their credibility, the governments risk their chance of additional loans, and a currency crisis may easily be triggered. o The fourth lesson is; the impact of Political Uncertainty and Instability. Overwhelming financial difficulties will need a precise action and precaution to be taken by the government in order to stabilize the current situation.

Then the governments should convince the opposing parties in the Parliament, bureaucrats and the public to form a political consensus. But this will not be enough, because one or more of these mentioned groups may conclude the government is incapable of such responsibilities. As in every crisis there are losers, some new distributional consequences will occur. And even these losers should be convinced by the government to minimise their losses and risks. It should be always kept in mind that, government failures can't be hidden from the public and markets for good. Always remember that the crisis can only be over when the uncertainty concerns regarding the economic policy ends. o The fifth lesson is the disorder of public and private domestic financial and real sector institutions.

The close and unhealthy relations between the governments and private sector bear a risk of hampering effective competition which is usually weaker in the developing economies. Weakened banks will face a harsh liquidity crisis. This stands as the unavoidable outcome of a run in the local currency. If the running deepens, at that point foreign creditors will tend to cut new credits and even demand repayment of the maturing loans immediately.

What's worse, the domestic banks may demand repayment of their short- term loans from the real sector, in such a time that both the real sector and the country needs export loans the most. That's what's happening and will happen in the second and third quarter of 2002 in Turkey. If the governments tend to overcome the crisis by re-establishing the domestic financial system by huge amounts of foreign debts, foreign control over the domestic mechanism will be increased. o The sixth lesson is the impact of corruption, both on the economic and political environment. The duty losses of the state banks, hollowed private banks, bad loans, rampant corruption, rent-seekers and their targets of influencing SOE's and hollowing their liabilities all make up the same maelstrom. This has already led a new way of life; petty corruption be popularized among small - timers in the last two decades.

However, governments- if they are determined to fight corruption - will have two fronts in this battle; the corrupt elite getting the big share and too many ordinary people - including the example of several million people consuming illegal electricity in their homes and shops, which is estimated to cost the economy approximately 3 billion US$ Per annum- resisting this battle. The latter are well aware of the corruption but still insist on these practices to get by. Therefore, governments should prevent the big sharers first, in order to maintain confidence in the public.

Bibliography

Corbett, Jenny and Mitchell, Janet, 'Banking Crises and Bank Rescues: The Effect of Reputation,' ' Working Paper No 290, January 2000, William Davidson Institute.
o Feldstein, Martin 'Refocusing the IMF,' Foreign Affairs, March / April 1998, pp.
20-33. o Harris- White, Barbara and White, Gordon (eds. ), 'Liberalization and the New Corruption,' ' IDS Bulletin, Vol. 27 No: 2, 1996 o Nas, F.
Tevfik and Odeon, Mehmet (eds.) ' Liberalization and the Turkish Economy' 1988, Greenwood Publishing Group.
o Rittenberg, Libby, (ed.) 'The Political Economy of Turkey in the Post-Soviet Era: Going West and Looking East?' ' 1998 Praeger Publishing Shaker, Sallam a State, Society and Privatisation in Turkey, 1979-1990 (Woodrow Wilson Center Special Studies) 1995 Johns Hopkins Univ.
Pr. o To gan, Subidey, Balasubramanyam, V.N. (Eds.) 'The Economy of Turkey Since Liberalization,' ' 1996 Palgrave Publishing.
o User, E. Murat ' Monetary Policy Practice in Turkey: From the 1994 Crisis to the Present.
October 1999, mime o, Credit Suisse First Boston, Emerging Markets Economic Research Vishwanath, T.
and Kaufmann, D. 'Toward Transparency: New Approaches and their Application to Financial Markets', The World Bank Research Observer, Volume 16, No. 1, Spring 2001.